The Role of Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations (2024)

The 2008–09 global financial crisis and ensuing worldwide recession have brought renewed attention to the importance of credit conditions for the macroeconomy. From a theoretical perspective, two broad mechanisms link credit conditions to macroeconomic outcomes.

First, financial frictions on the side of borrowers imply that their borrowing costs include an external finance premium — the cost of borrowing above and beyond the relevant risk-free interest rate. Theory tells us that this external finance premium should vary with the net worth of the borrower relative to the amount borrowed — in effect, higher borrower leverage implies greater borrowing costs. During an economic downturn, the external finance premium increases as asset prices fall and leverage rises; this increase in borrowing costs causes a reduction in spending by households and firms, which further exacerbates the downturn.

Second, conditional on the quality of borrowers' balance sheets, the supply of credit offered by financial intermediaries may also vary over the cycle, rising in booms and falling in recessions. Financial disruptions reduce credit supply and cause borrowing costs to rise, conditional on the default characteristics of the borrowers. Broadly speaking, my work in this area uses information on borrowers' costs obtained from corporate bond prices to understand the role of credit supply fluctuations in determining economic outcomes.

The Predictive Content of Credit Spreads

To identify disruptions in credit markets, research on the role of asset prices in economic fluctuations has focused on the information content of various corporate credit spreads. This prior research, however, finds mixed results in the ability of credit spreads to forecast economic activity. A limitation of this literature is its reliance on aggregate credit spread indices that allow for a significant mismatch in the maturity composition of corporate bond yields and their risk-free Treasury counterparts. In effect, such series mix duration risk with credit risk.

In my first paper on this topic, Vladimir Yankov, Egon Zakrajšek, and I provide evidence that credit spreads are robust forecasters of economic activity, using a broad array of credit spreads constructed directly from the secondary bond prices on outstanding senior unsecured debt issued by a large panel of nonfinancial firms.1 This allows us to construct a credit spread for each bond outstanding, based on comparing the bond price to that of a synthetic risk-free Treasury security with matched cash flows. This "ground-up" approach solves the problem of maturity mismatch when constructing credit-spread indices.

An additional advantage of this ground-up approach is that we are able to construct matched portfolios of equity returns, allowing us to examine the information content of bond spreads that is independent of the information contained in stock prices of the same set of firms, as well as in macroeconomic variables measuring economic activity, inflation, interest rates, and other financial indicators. We document that our portfolio-based bond spreads contain substantial predictive power for economic activity and outperform — especially at longer horizons — standard credit-risk indicators.

This analysis is conducted using standard in-sample forecasting methods. A follow- up paper written with Jon Faust, Jonathan Wright, and Zakrajšek employs a large number of real and financial indicators to forecast real-time measures of economic activity within a Bayesian Model Averaging (BMA) framework.2 Our results indicate that BMA yields consistent improvements in the prediction of real activity measures, at horizons from the current quarter ("nowcasting") out to four quarters hence. The gains in forecast accuracy owe exclusively to the inclusion of our portfolio credit spreads in the set of predictors. Put differently, BMA consistently assigns a high posterior weight to models that include these financial indicators.

The Excess Bond Premium

An important question is the extent to which the predictive content of credit spreads occurs because of credit demand, including the cyclical variation in borrowers' credit risk, as opposed to variation in the willingness of bond holders to bear such risk, which we believe relates to credit-supply considerations.

To address this issue, Zakrajšek and I follow the same ground-up approach to construct a single index of credit spreads — the Gilchrist-Zakrajšek (GZ) spread — based on all available bond data outstanding dating back to 1973.3 Using a flexible empirical framework, we then decompose this credit spread into two parts: a component reflecting the available firm-specific information on default risk and the excess bond premium (EBP), a residual component that can be thought of as capturing investor attitudes toward corporate credit risk — that is, credit market sentiment. In effect, the EBP tries to capture the variation in the average price of bearing U.S. corporate credit risk, above and beyond the compensation that investors in the corporate bond market require for expected defaults.

The Role of Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations (1)

Figure 1 shows these two credit-risk indicators from January 1973 through October 2018. Both the GZ credit spread and the EBP increase significantly prior to, or during, most of the cyclical downturns since the early 1970s. In addition, both indicators reach an all-time high at the peak of the financial turmoil associated with the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008.

A closer look at the excess bond premium in the period prior to the Lehman collapse offers a significant insight. Notably, the EBP is at its lowest point during the 2003–06 period, which is often viewed as a period of excessive risk-taking in the financial sector. The EBP begins to increase in early 2007, concomitant with the slowdown in home prices and rising concerns regarding the quality of commercial paper backed by securitized mortgage assets. These concerns substantially predate significant evidence of an impending slowdown in economic activity. In this sense, the EBP captures well the investor sentiment in the corporate bond market, as well as in other markets for risky assets, in the run-up to the financial crisis.

Using the GZ credit spread, we again document the ability of credit spreads to predict a wide range of real activity variables at both the one-quarter and one-year horizons. Focusing on data since the mid-1980s, a period that saw a substantial deepening of the U.S. corporate bond market, our results indicate that the excess bond premium accounts for all of the forecasting power of credit spreads for macroeconomic outcomes.

Such forecasting exercises do not allow a causal interpretation. Using standard identification methods from the structural vector autoregression (VAR) literature, we further document that innovations in the EBP that are orthogonal to the current state of the economy lead to significant declines in economic activity and equity prices. In quantitative terms, these estimates are on a par with the estimated effects of contractionary monetary policy shocks.

We also show that during the 2007–09 financial crisis, a deterioration in the creditworthiness of broker-dealers — who are key financial intermediaries in the corporate cash market — led to an increase in the excess bond premium. These findings support the notion that a rise in the EBP represents a reduction in the effective risk-bearing capacity of the financial sector and, as a result, a contraction in the supply of credit that has significant adverse consequences for the macroeconomy.

Recession Probabilities

More recent work with Giovani Favara, Kurt Lewis, and Zakrajšek focuses on the ability of the excess bond premium to predict National Bureau of Economic Research-dated recessions, using a standard binary recession indicator approach.4 The leading statistical model in this area relies on a combination of the real federal funds rate and the term spread as the two primary recession predictors. Consistent with our prior results, we document that the GZ credit spread contains significant information — above and beyond these two variables — for recession risk over the 1973-2016 sample period. We further document that over the past four decades, the predictive power of credit spreads for economic downturns is due entirely to the EBP. Moreover, a model based solely on the EBP explains over half of the total variation captured by the broader model that includes the additional interest rate series.

The Role of Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations (2)

To see the predictive content of the excess bond premium for recession outcomes, Figure 2 plots the implied recession probabilities from a statistical model that relies solely on the excess bond premium. In the post-1985 sample period, the EBP captures most of the variation in recession probabilities implied by such a framework. It also predicts the onset of the 2007–09 recession very well.

European Evidence

In other recent work, Benoit Mojon and I follow the same ground-up approach to construct credit risk indicators for euro-area banks and nonfinancial corporations.5

These indicators reveal that the financial crisis of 2008 dramatically increased the cost of market funding for both banks and nonfinancial firms in the euro area. The 2008 financial crisis also led to a systematic divergence in credit spreads for financial firms across national boundaries. Credit spreads for financial institutions in the periphery countries, Spain and Italy, widened considerably relative to their counterparts in the core countries such as France and Germany. This divergence in cross-country credit risk increased further as the European sovereign debt crisis intensified in 2010. This dramatic widening of such spreads in the periphery relative to the core of the euro zone reflects the disruptions to credit supply experienced by the periphery, as rising concerns regarding sovereign default risk spilled over into the private sector.

Consistent with this view, we show that credit spreads provide substantial predictive content for a variety of real activity and lending measures for the euro area as a whole and for individual countries. Again, using structural VAR methods to determine causality, our analysis implies that disruptions in corporate credit markets lead to sizable contractions in output, increases in unemployment, and declines in inflation across the euro area.

Causes of the Great Recession

An important question is why the fall in home prices and the resulting financial turmoil had such severe economic consequences during the Great Recession. One answer is that falling home prices led to a sharp reduction in spending by households, owing both to wealth effects and to households' propensity to borrow against housing wealth. An alternative view is that declining home prices led to financial sector losses and a sharp, broad-based decline in credit available to both firms and households.

In a recent paper, Mark Gertler and I seek to assess the relative strength of these mechanisms within a panel data VAR framework.6 Household balance sheet effects during the crisis are identified through state-specific responses of employment to variation in home prices due to the differential degree to which households are indebted across geographic regions prior to the crisis. Conditional on such response, we then exploit time-variation in the EBP for financial sector bonds to capture an aggregate component that may be attributed to the broad-based declines in credit supply that are not specific to the household sector.

The Role of Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations (3)

Figure 3 shows the resulting historical decomposition of aggregate employment into the usual effect of housing prices over the cycle that primarily affects construction employment, the household balance sheet effect specific to the Great Recession, and the effect of an aggregate reduction in credit supply as captured by the excess bond premium. This decomposition implies that contractions in the aggregate supply of credit, as measured by increases in the EBP, account for over 50 percent of the overall decline in employment during the 2007–10 period.

While much work remains to be done studying the link between credit conditions and economic activity, my research suggests that credit spreads forecast economic activity across a wide variety of settings. Moreover, the evidence suggests that disruptions in credit supply, as measured by variation in the excess bond premium, are a primary factor contributing to adverse economic outcomes. The fact that the excess bond premium rises prior to recessions and helps predict recession outcomes suggests that credit supply plays an important role in shaping the business cycle, and accounts for a large fraction of the overall decline in economic activity during the Great Recession.

The Role of Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations (2024)

FAQs

The Role of Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations? ›

During an economic downturn, the external finance premium increases as asset prices fall and leverage rises; this increase in borrowing costs causes a reduction in spending by households and firms, which further exacerbates the downturn.

What are the causes and effects of economic fluctuations? ›

Every nation's economy fluctuates between periods of expansion and contraction. These changes are caused by levels of employment, productivity, and the total demand for and supply of the nation's goods and services. In the short-run, these changes lead to periods of expansion and recession.

What are some of the key reasons for short run economic fluctuations? ›

In the short run, shifts in aggregate demand cause fluctuations in the economy's output of goods and services. In the long run, shifts in aggregate demand affect the overall price level but do not affect output. Aggregate supply shifts the curve to the left when: Output falls below the natural rate of employment.

What is used to describe fluctuations in the economy? ›

Economists use the term business cycle to describe the ups and downs, or fluctuations, in an economy. More specifically, the term refers to the fluctuating levels of economic activity over a period of time measured from the beginning of one recession to the beginning of the next.

What are the three properties of economic fluctuations? ›

The characteristics of economic fluctuations include the following: Fluctuations are repetitive in nature like waves. Variables such as employment and consumption rise and fall at times. Prices tend to be highly variable; profits decline in recession and increase in a boom.

What are the effects of economic fluctuations? ›

Fluctuations in the total output of a nation (GDP) affect unemployment, and unemployment is a serious hardship for people. Economists measure the size of the economy using the national accounts: these measure economic fluctuations and growth.

What are the causes of financial instability? ›

Four factors typically help initiate financial instability: (1) increases in interest rates, (2) a deterioration in bank balance sheets, (3) negative shocks to nonbank balance sheets such as a stock market decline, and (4) increases in uncer- tainty.

What is an example of a financial instability? ›

Stock market crashes, credit crunches, the bursting of financial bubbles, sovereign defaults, and currency crises are all examples of financial crises. A financial crisis may be limited to a single country or one segment of financial services, but is more likely to spread regionally or globally.

What are 4 things that cause economic instability? ›

Causes of economic instability include stock market fluctuations, fluctuations in the prices of houses and other assets, black swan events (unexpected disasters that impact the economy), and changes in interest rates.

What causes most short-run economic fluctuations demand or supply shocks? ›

In addition, the position of the short-run aggregate supply curve depends on the expected price level. One possible cause of economic fluctuations is a shift in aggregate demand. When the aggregate-demand curve shifts to the left, output and prices fall in the short run.

What is another name for short-run economic fluctuations? ›

Here's the best way to solve it. The correct answer is business cycles. Short-run economic fluctuations are commonly referred to as b...

How can exogenous factors cause economic fluctuations? ›

Exogenous causes are factors that influence the business cycle from outside of the system, e.g. climate (drought and other natural disasters) and the political situation of a country. Endogenous causes are factors that influence the business cycle from inside the system, e.g. total expenditure.

Are economic fluctuations easy to predict? ›

Irregular; difficult . Reason: In an economy, the short-run fluctuations are very irregular and bring uncertain conditions with them. These fluctuations are generally present for a short period of time and due to this, it is difficult to analyze and predict them in a proper way.

Are economic fluctuations easily predicted? ›

Future fluctuation in economics is not so easy; none of the economists can estimate the changes in the economy. Expenses, revenue, and production will affect the Gross Domestic Product.

What is business fluctuation in economics? ›

Business fluctuations are increases and decreases in economic activity, as measured by increases and decreases in real GDP. A recession (or contraction) is defined as a decrease in real GDP of at least two consecutive quarters (6 months). An expansion is any period of time during which real GDP is increasing.

What are the 4 factors that affect fluctuations in the business cycle? ›

Key takeaways: The business cycle refers to the increases and decreases in economic activity caused by factors like interest rates, trade, production costs and investments. The four fundamental stages of the business cycle are expansion, peak, contraction and trough.

What are the five factors of economic change? ›

Economic factors include economic growth, percentage of unemployment, inflation, interest and exchange rates, and commodity (oil, steel, gold, etc) prices. These affect the discretionary income and purchasing power of households and organisations alike.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Errol Quitzon

Last Updated:

Views: 6622

Rating: 4.9 / 5 (59 voted)

Reviews: 90% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Errol Quitzon

Birthday: 1993-04-02

Address: 70604 Haley Lane, Port Weldonside, TN 99233-0942

Phone: +9665282866296

Job: Product Retail Agent

Hobby: Computer programming, Horseback riding, Hooping, Dance, Ice skating, Backpacking, Rafting

Introduction: My name is Errol Quitzon, I am a fair, cute, fancy, clean, attractive, sparkling, kind person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.